Close Menu
World Economist – Global Markets, Finance & Economic Insights
  • Home
  • Economist Impact
    • Economist Intelligence
    • Finance & Economics
  • Business
  • Asia
  • China
  • Europe
  • Economy
  • USA
    • Middle East & Africa
    • Highlights
  • This week
  • World Economy
    • World News
What's Hot

Chinese lidar maker Hesai to pour Hong Kong listing proceeds into expanding production

September 16, 2025

Chinese start-up breaks US monopoly in 3D imaging of biomolecules, aims for IPO in 2027

September 16, 2025

What are investors expecting from the strangest Federal Reserve meeting in years?

September 16, 2025
Facebook X (Twitter) Instagram
Tuesday, September 16
Facebook X (Twitter) Instagram
World Economist – Global Markets, Finance & Economic Insights
  • Home
  • Economist Impact
    • Economist Intelligence
    • Finance & Economics
  • Business
  • Asia
  • China
  • Europe
  • Economy
  • USA
    • Middle East & Africa
    • Highlights
  • This week
  • World Economy
    • World News
World Economist – Global Markets, Finance & Economic Insights
Home » In praise of America’s trade deficit
USA

In praise of America’s trade deficit

adminBy adminMay 15, 2025No Comments8 Mins Read
Share Facebook Twitter Pinterest Copy Link LinkedIn Tumblr Email VKontakte Telegram
Share
Facebook Twitter Pinterest Email Copy Link
Post Views: 48


This article is an on-site version of Free Lunch newsletter. Premium subscribers can sign up here to get the newsletter delivered every Thursday and Sunday. Standard subscribers can upgrade to Premium here, or explore all FT newsletters

I have had two takes on US President Donald Trump’s trade war in the past month. First, I pointed out that too many people accept the dubious claim that reducing the trade deficit will boost manufacturing, and explained why we should be sceptical. Second, I wrote about how a tax on imports hurts exports just as much (maybe more, as suggested by some modelling of Trump’s tariffs), so we shouldn’t expect it to reduce the trade deficit.

I hope you will indulge me for a third go. Lost in all the commentary are the strong reasons why the US should actually want to maintain its trade deficit and why everyone else might treat it with benign neglect. So this week, Free Lunch rectifies that omission. Share your reactions at freelunch@ft.com.

It is taken as axiomatic, way beyond Trumpian circles, that global financial “imbalances” are a bad thing. (Why the scare quotes? I don’t like the word “imbalance” because it seems to presuppose unsustainability: something out of balance can’t remain in that position for long. I prefer “asymmetries” as a more neutrally descriptive term.)

But external surpluses and deficits reflect domestic saving and investment decisions. Economies that save more than they invest run external net surpluses (those extra goods they export over those they import pay for building up claims on capital abroad). Those that invest more than they save run external net deficits (those extra goods they import over those they export makes it possible to invest without cutting consumption as much, while building up liabilities to where the extra goods come from).

This is the modern view of international economics: external “imbalances” are a function of macroeconomics, not of trade. Seen in a different light, net trade patterns are caused by financial flows and not the other way round. That’s another reason why, as I wrote last week, we shouldn’t expect trade policy to have much effect on net deficits or surplus. (Trade policy can and does affect gross bilateral trade flows, of course, as well as changing how trade affects specific sectors such as semiconductors.)

Our default judgment about how appropriate those savings and investment decisions are should, I think, be neutral or positive. Countries make different decisions (through individual market action and public policy) about whether to be net savers or net borrowers. If a global financial and trade market makes all those desires compatible, that, in principle, gets every country what it wants, subject to making it compatible with what others want. The burden of proof is surely on those who want to criticise those domestic decisions.

There are some obvious arguments that I’ll mention to put aside. One is that a government may make what we think of as bad choices. So a relatively poor country such as China could let its citizens consume more without investing less. Or it may not reflect our political or democratic sensibilities. So US elites did not for a long time have the interests of declining manufacturing areas at heart. These are valid critiques — of politically constrained domestic decisions. They are not valid critiques of the global financial and trading system.

Such a critique would have to claim that there is something inherent to the system that makes it too difficult for a country to make the best choices for it.

In the short run, there is a sensible Keynesian version of such an argument: a country that cuts domestic demand and hence imports, or acts to strongly expand exports and generate demand from other countries’ consumers, can cause slowdowns, recessions or unemployment in other countries which may not have the fiscal or other means to counteract it. Hence the label “beggar-thy-neighbour” policy. But to repeat: this can only be a short-term phenomenon. It is not an argument against long-term structural asymmetries, those that persist through the business cycle, including in times of full employment.

And yet, there is a highly popular belief that China and other structural surplus economies force the US to run a structural deficit. When you pause to think about it, this is an odd view. Beijing’s policies no doubt aim to shape China’s net surplus. But why think of this as forcing Americans to do anything, rather than offering them a cheaper-than-otherwise opportunity to consume and invest more, if they want to?

If Americans wanted to balance their external account, they could do so in many ways; most easily through a revenue-neutral tax reform that would provide an incentive to domestic business investment and reduce consumption. The fact that they choose not to do so suggests that they rather like the benefits that come with a structural trade deficit. And they are right, as we should be tempted to agree when we look at what those benefits are.

An external deficit means you can invest more than you save; ie you don’t have to cut consumption as much. For the US, this “more” amounts to about $1tn a year of foreign-funded US investment, or just over 3 per cent of GDP. For comparison, total business investment is close to 14 per cent. As the chart below shows, EU businesses invest a solid 1 per cent of GDP less — and the bloc has a structural net surplus.

Line chart of Business fixed capital formation as percentage of GDP showing US corporates out-invest EU ones

What is more, 1 per cent of GDP is also how much more US businesses spend on research and development compared with their EU peers. And total US R&D spending has grown from about 2.8 per cent of GDP a decade ago to 3.6 per cent today, just while the external deficit expanded too. It is hard to avoid the conclusion that the US’s structural net inflow of capital is precisely what affords America its current innovative edge.

For example, it allows the US to burn enormous amounts of cash to build data centres to train the large language models that have hit the world like a Sputnik flyover — without reducing consumption to fund those capital expenditures. Those amounts are set to exceed $300bn just this year. So that’s about a third of the current account deficit right there. 

For another example — this one to do with the semiconductor and green industry incentives of Bidenomics — construction spending on manufacturing facilities tripled (in nominal terms) to $240bn during the period of a widening trade deficit. Again, foreigners funded several hundred billion in hopefully productivity-enhancing investments, so that Americans did not need to sacrifice current consumption for future return.

The point is that these — and many more investments — are things America is delighted to have. But without the external deficit, it would only be able to have them if it curtailed consumption. That is not an attractive alternative, judging from the recent slump in Trump’s popularity.

What about the rest of the world? By running surpluses with the US, they are building up claims on the US economy. But more importantly, they are letting American businesses take the risk on the big investments that are not, as a result, being made in surplus economies. Whether that’s smart depends on your view of the risk. Massive capital spending to train LLMs will bring fortunes if the spenders can reap the return — but if they are just providing the early investments that everyone else can then just cheaply replicate, such as China’s DeepSeek, they will simply have subsidised the rest of the world. Something similar can be said for pharmaceutical research.

So whether the rest of the world should be happy about the US sucking in investment funding depends on their assessment of the risks — but this is no systemic critique of “imbalances”, and there is a strong case for being grateful to America. Meanwhile, there are fewer ambiguities about how the deficit benefits the US. It’s like Trump’s old fever dream of building a big, beautiful wall and forcing Mexico to pay for it, except much more valuable and it’s Europe and China lending the money without having to be asked.

Other readables

Recommended newsletters for you

Chris Giles on Central Banks — Your essential guide to money, interest rates, inflation and what central banks are thinking. Sign up here

India Business Briefing — The Indian professional’s must-read on business and policy in the world’s fastest-growing large economy. Sign up here



Source link

Share. Facebook Twitter Pinterest LinkedIn Tumblr Email Telegram Copy Link
admin
  • Website

Related Posts

USA

Why Intel investors have embraced an interventionist White House

August 28, 2025
USA

Trump’s attack on the Fed threatens US credibility

August 27, 2025
USA

The next stage of the Fed takeover

August 27, 2025
USA

Surging US electricity prices put Trump pledge in jeopardy

August 27, 2025
USA

EU moves to shield aluminium from Trump tariff blow

August 27, 2025
USA

Donald Trump’s battle against the Fed heads for courtroom showdown

August 26, 2025
Add A Comment
Leave A Reply Cancel Reply

Editors Picks

KE CEO Alvi proposes 100-year Sukuk listing at Pakistan Stock Exchange – Markets

September 16, 2025

Trump says US has a buyer for TikTok – Technology

September 16, 2025

PM Shehbaz inaugurates Mashreq Digital Bank, calls it ‘milestone’ for Pakistan’s economy – Business & Finance

September 16, 2025

PIA posts first H1 pre-tax profit in about two decades – Pakistan

September 16, 2025
Latest Posts

PSX hits all-time high as proposed ‘neutral-to-positive’ budget well-received by investors – Business

June 11, 2025

Sindh govt to allocate funds for EV taxis, scooters in provincial budget: minister – Pakistan

June 11, 2025

US, China reach deal to ease export curbs, keep tariff truce alive – World

June 11, 2025

Subscribe to News

Subscribe to our newsletter and never miss our latest news

Subscribe my Newsletter for New Posts & tips Let's stay updated!

Recent Posts

  • Chinese lidar maker Hesai to pour Hong Kong listing proceeds into expanding production
  • Chinese start-up breaks US monopoly in 3D imaging of biomolecules, aims for IPO in 2027
  • What are investors expecting from the strangest Federal Reserve meeting in years?
  • Ripple rises 2% on market optimism about US rate decision
  • Announcing canal revamp, Panama dodges questions about Chinese ownership

Recent Comments

No comments to show.

Welcome to World-Economist.com, your trusted source for in-depth analysis, expert insights, and the latest news on global finance and economics. Our mission is to provide readers with accurate, data-driven reports that shape the understanding of economic trends worldwide.

Latest Posts

Chinese lidar maker Hesai to pour Hong Kong listing proceeds into expanding production

September 16, 2025

Chinese start-up breaks US monopoly in 3D imaging of biomolecules, aims for IPO in 2027

September 16, 2025

What are investors expecting from the strangest Federal Reserve meeting in years?

September 16, 2025

Subscribe to Updates

Subscribe to our newsletter and never miss our latest news

Subscribe my Newsletter for New Posts & tips Let's stay updated!

Archives

  • September 2025
  • August 2025
  • July 2025
  • June 2025
  • May 2025
  • April 2025
  • March 2025
  • February 2025
  • January 2025
  • December 2024
  • June 2024
  • October 2022
  • March 2022
  • July 2021
  • February 2021
  • January 2021
  • November 2019
  • April 2011
  • January 2011
  • December 2007
  • July 2007

Categories

  • AI & Tech
  • Asia
  • Banking
  • Business
  • Business
  • China
  • Climate
  • Computing
  • Economist Impact
  • Economist Intelligence
  • Economy
  • Editor's Choice
  • Europe
  • Europe
  • Featured
  • Featured Business
  • Featured Climate
  • Featured Health
  • Featured Science & Tech
  • Featured Travel
  • Finance & Economics
  • Health
  • Highlights
  • Markets
  • Middle East
  • Middle East & Africa
  • Middle East News
  • Most Viewed News
  • News Highlights
  • Other News
  • Politics
  • Russia
  • Science
  • Science & Tech
  • Social
  • Space Science
  • Sports
  • Sports Roundup
  • Tech
  • This week
  • Top Featured
  • Travel
  • Trending Posts
  • Ukraine Conflict
  • Uncategorized
  • US Politics
  • USA
  • World
  • World & Politics
  • World Economy
  • World News
© 2025 world-economist. Designed by world-economist.
  • Home
  • About Us
  • Advertise With Us
  • Contact Us
  • DMCA
  • Privacy Policy
  • Terms & Conditions

Type above and press Enter to search. Press Esc to cancel.